SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
 issue5Economic Freedom and World Economic Growth: Evidence and ImplicationsUn programa piloto de crédito en el contexto del desarrollo alternativo: teoría y praxis author indexsubject indexarticles search
Home Pagealphabetic serial listing  

Services on Demand

Journal

Article

Indicators

Related links

  • Have no similar articlesSimilars in SciELO

Share


Revista Latinoamericana de Desarrollo Económico

Print version ISSN 2074-4706On-line version ISSN 2309-9038

rlde  no.5 La Paz Oct. 2005

 

TRABAJOS DE INVESTIGACIÓN

 

Long Run Money Neutrality: The Case of Guatemala

 

 

Frederick H. Wallace*

 

 


Abstract

The Fisher and Seater (1993) methodology is used to test for the long run neutrality of money in Guatemala, 1950-2001. Real GDP, real per capita GDP, and the money measures, M1 and M2, are integrated of order one [I(1)]. Given these orders of integration, the Fisher-Seater neutrality test can be applied. The evidence suggests that M1 and M2 are neutral with respect to real GDP. Furthermore, the test indicates that M1, but not M2, is neutral with respect to real per capita GDP as well.


Resumen**

La metodología de Fisher y Seater (1993) es utilizada para analizar la neutralidad del dinero en el largo plazo en Guatemala, 1950-2001. El PIB Real, PIB Real per capita, y las medidas del dinero. M1 y M2, son variables integradas de orden uno [I(1)]. Dados estos ordenes de integración, el test de neutralidad de Fisher y Seater puede ser aplicado. La evidencia sugiere que tanto M1 como M2 son neutrales respecto al PIB Real. De otra manera, el test tambien indica que solamente M1 es neutral con respecto al PIB Real per capita.


 

 

1. Introduction

Most economists accept the proposition that money is neutral in the long run. That is, a permanent and unexpected change in the quantity of money has no long run real effects. Fisher and Seater (1993) have developed a simple empirical test of the long run neutrality (LRN) proposition under the assumption that money is exogenous. The test depends on the orders of integration of the variables. Both money and the real variable must be integrated of, at least, order one to conduct the LRN test. The intuition is straightforward. If money is I(0), then there have been only temporary changes in money and it makes no sense to test for neutrality in the absence of sustained changes in the money stock. If, however, the real variable is I(0) and money is, say, I(1) then LRN cannot be rejected because there have been no permanent changes in the real variable. The FS neutrality test and the superneutrality variant have been widely used in recent years although mostly with data for industrialized countries.

The purpose of this study is to apply the FS test of long run money neutrality to real output in Guatemala. The macroeconomic performance of Guatemala has by no means been exemplary, but by Latin American standards it has been better than most. Although the Guatemalan economy has not been beset by such problems as hyperinflation and exchange rate crises that one often associates with Latin America, the country has been anything but tranquil politically. An extended civil war and several military coups occurred during the study period, 1950-2002.

Interestingly, given the theoretical appeal of the LRN proposition, use of the Fisher and Seater (FS) test for long run neutrality has yielded ambiguous results. FS find that LRN does not hold for the US for 1869-1975. Boschen and Otrok (1994) show that the FS results for the US are sensitive to the inclusion of data from the Great Depression years. Their findings indicate that money is LRN in the US for 1869-1929 and 1940-1992 sub-periods. They speculate that the large number of US bank failures during the Great Depression accounts for the rejection in the sample that includes 1930-1939. Haug and Lucas (1997) note that Canada did not have a single bank failure in the 1930-1939 period yet their results indicate that money is not LRN in Canada for the 1914-1994 period. LRN holds when a dummy variable for the Great Depression in included in the FS test leading Haug and Lucas to conclude that relation of money and output was unusual in Canada, as in the US, during the Great Depression period despite the absence of bank failures.

Olekalns (1996) finds that LRN holds for Australia when using a narrow measure of money but not for a broader measure. Similarly, Coe and Nason (2002) find mixed support for LRN. Using a longer sample period than Haug and Lucas, they reject LRN for Canada. Coe and Nason fail to reject LRN for Australia and the US when using the monetary base but reject LRN when a broader money stock measure is employed. Finally, their evidence supports neutrality for the United Kingdom.

Wallace (1999) finds that both Ml and M2 are long run neutral for the 1932-1992 period in Mexico. In contrast Noriega (2001) concludes that M1 is not neutral in Mexico for the extended period 1932-2000. Shelley and Wallace (2003) also conclude that money, regardless of the measure, is not LRN in Mexico for 1932-2002 but that this result arises from inclusion of the 1982-1986 period of high money growth and inflation in the data. For 1932-1981, money is LRN in Mexico1.

The mixed empirical evidence for LRN is surprising in light of the strong theoretical appeal of the proposition. In several of the studies in which LRN is rejected, periods of aberrant economic performance (severe recession or high inflation) are included. These anomalous periods appear to be driving the rejection of the proposition. The Boschen and Otrok results for the US, the Haug and Lucas findings for Canada, and the Shelley and Wallace study for Mexico can be interpreted in this fashion. As previously noted, Guatemala has been relatively stable economically but not politically. Can political instability, unaccompanied by severe macroeconomic problems, also cause a rejection of the long run neutrality proposition?. In the case of Guatemala, the answer appears to be no.

 

2. Data

Real GDP figures for 1980-2002 and Ml and M2 money stock data for 1950-2002 are available from the Banco de Guatemala, the country's central bank. The bank also reports annual real growth rates for 1950-2002. The real growth rates are used to estimate real GDP data for the 1950-1979 period. These constructed figures are appended to the 1980-2002 series available from the bank. Since the real GDP data are, in part, constructed from the central bank's growth rate statistics, the FS test is also applied to an alternative output measure, real per capita GDP for 1950-2000 from the Penn World Tables [Heston, Summers, and Bettina (2002)], as a robustness check.

Economic growth (real GDP) averaged nearly 4 percent annually while inflation averaged slightly more than 7.5 percent each year of the study period. Even at its worst, 60.6 percent in 1990, inflation never presented the serious problem it did in other Latin American countries. In only two other years in the sample period did inflation exceed 20 percent. However Guatemala has been beset by political turmoil, military coups and civil war. Consequently its growth performance has been erratic. Figure 1 shows the growth rates of real GDP and M1 over the study period. Table 1 presents these growth rates and those for the price level and real per capita GDP for three sub-periods.

 

As can be seen from the figure and table the growth rate of real output diminished sharply in the 1981 -1986 period, averaging slightly less than a 1 percent annual decrease in real GDP. The effect of the poor economic performance during this period is even more starkly reflected in the average annual decline of -2.27 percent in real per capita GDP. M1 growth averaged 9 percent annually from 1951-1980. Given the 5 percent mean growth rate in real GDP and the nearly 4 percent mean growth rate in the price level, the 9 percent rate of Ml growth suggests a stable demand for money. The money stock as measured by M2 (not shown) grew much more rapidly on average during the 1951 -1980 period than the price level. It is interesting to note that in none of the three sub-periods did the average annual increase in the price level exceed the mean rate of money growth. Thus, it appears that money demand was either stable (M1) or growing (M2) throughout the study period.

In the Fisher-Seater procedure, the orders of integration of the variables determine whether LRN can be tested and, if testable, the appropriate form of the test. All variables used in the study are logged. Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) and Phillips-Perron (PP) unit root tests are employed to determine the orders of variable integration. Unit root tests in levels include a constant and a trend. Unit root tests on the first differences of variables include a trend if a regression of the first difference on a constant and trend shows that the trend is significant2. Beginning with zero lags of the dependent variable, lags are added to the ADF equation until a Lagrange multiplier test indicates that serial correlation is eliminated. In all cases, the tests indicate that none of the variables is stationary in levels. But the hypothesis of a unit root in first differences can be rejected for all variables. Thus for the data used in this study, the ADF and PP test results clearly indicate that all output and money measures are I(1). However, the first differences of both (logged) money series contain significant trends, an issue addressed below.

Long run money exogeneity is an assumption of the Fisher-Seater approach. To examine this assumption, a Granger causality test is applied to the first differences of the logarithms of money and real output. The results (see Appendix 1) indicate that differenced real output does not Granger-cause either monetary variable. The test result suggests that money is likely to be exogenous. Although the absence of Granger causality is not a sufficient condition for exogeneity, a finding that output Granger-causes money would provide strong evidence against the assumption.

 

3. Fisher-Seater Test and Empirical Results

Fisher and Seater show that equation (1) can be used to test for LRN if both (logged) money, m, and the (logged) real variable, y, are I(1) and money is exogenous. In this case the estimator of the long run derivative of y with respect to a permanent change in m is the limit of the slope coefficient, bk, as k → ∞. A predetermined maximum of twenty or thirty periods is typically selected for k; k = 24 is used in this study. Equation (1) is estimated by OLS using the Newey-West (1994) correction for serial correlation In addition to the differenced logged money and output terms, a trend (t) is included to remove the effects of the trend in logged differenced money. The degrees of freedom in the FS test are T/k where T is the number of observations.

Figures 2 and 3 show the bk plots from estimation of equation (1) and the 95% confidence interval for real GDP and real per capita GDP, respectively, when M1 is the monetary variable. Except as noted, the results for M2 are very similar thus omitted3. In both graphs, zero is contained within the confidence interval for all values of k thus indicating that the hypothesis of long run neutrality of M1 with respect to either real aggregate or per capita GDP cannot be rejected4. The failure to reject long run neutrality of M1 appears robust, as the results for both total and per capita GDP are the same. Thus the construction of some of the values of the total GDP variable does not appear to affect the results.

The results using M2 and total GDP in equation (1) are qualitatively the same as those for M1. However, when using M2 and per capita GDP as the real output measure, four of the bk coefficients (k = 8...11) are significantly positive. This result may indicate that the LRN cannot be rejected for M1 but does not hold for M2. Such an interpretation would be consistent with that of Olekalns who finds that the FS test results for Australia are sensitive to the money measure used. This explanation appears unlikely since the FS test results indicate that M2 is LRN with respect to total GDP. Alternatively, the results with M2 may be attributable to the manner in which the per capita GDP is measured since the two GDP measures are from different data sources.

 

4. Conclusions

Application of the Fisher-Seater test of long run money neutrality to data for Guatemala indicates that the LRN proposition cannot be rejected for either real GDP or real per capita GDP when M1 is the money measure. It is puzzling that long run neutrality cannot be rejected for total GDP but cannot be accepted for per capita GDP when M2 is used. There is no obvious reason for such a difference. However, the bulk of the evidence suggests that LRN does hold.

The failure to reject the LRN proposition is particularly interesting in the case of Guatemala because the country was subjected to significant political turmoil during the sample period. Previous work by Boschen and Otrok, Haug and Lucas, and Shelley and Wallace suggest that periods of aberrant economic performance can lead to a rejection of LRN. However, at least in the case of Guatemala, it does not appear that political instability affects LRN. Not even a long running civil war and military coups are sufficient to generate a violation of the classical LRN proposition.

 

Notes

* Universidad de Quintana Roo, Chetumal, Mexico.

** La traducción del resumen del inglés al español es responsabilidad de los editores de la Revista Latinoamericana de Desarrollo Económico.

1    Shelley and Wallace show that Wallace's finding of LRN is caused by fhe use of data prior to 1932 in the generation of the differenced variables used in the FS test, even though the estimation sample is restricted to 1932-1992. Prior to 1932 gold circulated as money in Mexico thus money was unlikely to be exogenous, a necessary.

2    The Newey-West correction for serial correlation is applied in these regressions.

3    All coefficient estimates and standard errors are shown in Appendix 2.

4    The standard errors for the mid-range values of k tend to be large relative to other values of k. This difference accounts for the shape of the confidence interval.

 

REFERENCES

Ball, L and D. Romer. 2003. "Inflation and the Informativeness of Prices". Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking. 35: 1 77-196.

Boschen, J. F. and C.M. Otrok. 1994. "Long run Neutrality and Superneutrality in an ARIMA Framework: Comment". American Economic Review. 84 1 470-1473

Bruno. M and W. Easterly. 1998. "Inflation Crises and Long Run Growth" Journal of Monetary Economics. 41: 3-26.

Banco de Guatemala. 2003. "Información Económica". http://www.banguat.gob.gt/

Coe, P. J. andj. M. Nason. 2002. "The Long-horizon Regression Approach to Monetary Neutrality: How Should the Evidence Be Interpreted?". Economics Letters 78: 351-356.

Fisher, M. E. and J. J. Seater. 1993. "Long Run Neutrality and Superneutrality in an ARIMA Framework". American Economic Review. 83: 402-41 5.

Haug, A.A. and R. F. Lucas. 1997 "Long Run Neutrality and Superneutrality in an ARIMA Framework: Comment". American Economic Review. 87: 756-759.

Heston, A., R. Summers, and A. Bettina. 2002. "Penn World Table Version 6.1". Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP).

King, R. G. and M. W. Watson. 1997. "Testing Long run Neutrality". Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. Economic Quarterly 83: 69-100.

Newey, W. K. and K. D West. 1994. "A Simple, Positive Semi-definite, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix". Econometrica. 55: 703-708.

Olekalns, N. 1996. "Some Further Evidence on the Long Run Neutrality of Money". Economics Letters. 50: 393-398.

Shelley, G. L. and F. H. Wallace. 2003. "Testing for Long Run Neutrality of Money in Mexico". Unpublished working paper. Universidad de Quintana Roo, Chetumal, Mexico.

Wallace, F. H. 1999. "Long Run Neutrality of Money in the Mexican Economy". Applied Economics Letters. 6: 637-40.

Wu, Y. andj. Zhang. 1998. "Endogenous Growth and the Welfare Costs of Inflation: A Reconsideration". Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control. 22: 465-482.

 

Appendix 1

Granger Causality Test Results

 

 

Appendix 2

Coefficients and Standard Errors

 

Creative Commons License All the contents of this journal, except where otherwise noted, is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution License